Which of the following would not be part of the opportunity costs of going to college?

Understanding even basic economic principles can be tricky, and understanding opportunity cost is no different. Most of the explanations found online aren’t that helpful because they are often overly complicated. And if you’re like most people, you need a clear understanding of your options and how they stack up against each other – and you don’t have a ton of time to spend grappling with what should be a relatively simple concept.

In fact, economics is fairly simple. Economists tend to overcomplicate it with buzzwords and other jargon. So, in plain words, here is an explanation of the opportunity cost of attending college.

What is opportunity cost?

So there’s something you’d like to do. You know it’s going to take money and time. You can think of “opportunity cost” as the next best thing you could do with all that money and time. In this case, the opportunity cost of the project you want to take on is the money and time you’ll spend on it, plus whatever money, time, and enjoyment you’ll miss out on by not doing something else instead.

So, the opportunity cost is simply a way of analyzing your available choices. Your time and money are limited resources. You can make one of several different choices, but if you’re like most people, you only have enough time and money for one choice. Choosing option A means missing the value that option B (or C or D) would provide. Therefore, opportunity cost is what you’re missing out on by making a choice.

Why is it so important? Why should some confusing economic principle matter to you? Because it’s the key to understanding your individual life choices – as well as choices made by the government concerning your tax dollars. Opportunity cost allows you to understand the effects different choices have on your life.

Which of the following would not be part of the opportunity costs of going to college?

What does opportunity cost have to do with college?

Most people tend to think of college as a necessary step that can provide them with an education that more or less guarantees them a successful life with a well-paying job. It’s part of the American Dream, after all. Right?

Not so fast. Just like any life decision, college carries an opportunity cost. When you go to college, you give up other things – in fact, in some cases, you might have to give up quite a lot. The opportunity cost of college is huge, and it will probably have a much bigger effect on you than you realize.

College costs a lot no matter how you look at it. Whichever college you choose, no one would argue that college tuition was “cheap.” In fact, it costs more than you probably think. Tuition is only one part of the cost; the true cost of college also includes any outside expenses plus the income you’re forgoing by going to school instead of work.

Which of the following would not be part of the opportunity costs of going to college?

What could you do with that college tuition money instead?

If you didn’t go to college, could you work full time instead and save money to buy a car? If you’re going to college to study, say, photography, could you instead be learning in a hands-on environment under a professional photographer? The possibilities are endless. You could be on your way to becoming financially independent, rather than spending your time on school projects.

The essence of opportunity cost is what you choose to do versus what you choose not to do. You could spend a lot of money and time in college, sure. Or you could get an early start in your desired career, buy a car, and get started on the path to becoming stable and independent.

You can only be in one place at one time. When you choose to engage in one activity, you give up others. Now, you have your own ideas about what your best option is versus your next best option; so does everyone else. For one person, college might be option A while getting a job might be the next best option, option B. But for another person, working right out of high school might be option A while college is option B. Opportunity cost is subjective. You only have so much time and money to do things with, and you have your own opinions about what is desirable and what’s not.

Which of the following would not be part of the opportunity costs of going to college?

What is The Opportunity Cost Of Going To College?

In short, the opportunity cost of going to college is the cost of tuition, any associated costs, and any income, experience, and pleasure you miss out on because you choose to attend college. This cost naturally varies from person to person, depending on what they would choose to do instead of attending college and how much value (monetary or otherwise) that endeavor holds for them. It is based on the principle that you have a limited amount of time and money to do what you want, so you have to make choices. It’s up to you to choose between two different options and the financial gains and other benefits they bring.

Opportunity cost applies to all of the choices you make, not just whether or not you go to college. It’s a great way to help you understand the effect one choice has over another in your life. It can also help you analyze the value of each choice.

For a fun way to demonstrate this concept, try this: pick something you currently do or spend money on, and find its opportunity cost. It might be attending college, or it might be anything from staying up too late or buying a new video game to buying a new car or getting married. Just choose any activity or expense, and find its monetary cost – then make a list of things you could be doing instead with that money and time. What would your next best option be? How much enjoyment are you missing out on by making the choice you made? Compare the two options and determine whether you chose the right one.

College is not an automatic, necessary step in everyone’s life. Think about the opportunity cost involved before making a decision.

Use College Comparison Tool to Compare Your College Choices Now!

In microeconomic theory, the opportunity cost of a particular activity option is the loss of value or benefit that would be incurred (the cost) by engaging in that activity, relative to engaging in an alternative activity offering a higher return in value or benefit.

The smaller the opportunity cost, the greater the comparative advantage. For example, if you buy a car and use it exclusively for travel, you cannot rent it, whereas if you rent it you cannot use it for travel. More simply, it means you give up one thing for another.

In basic equation form, opportunity cost can be defined as:

Opportunity Cost = (returns on best Forgone Option) - (returns on Chosen Option)[1]

The opportunity cost of mowing one’s own lawn for a doctor or a lawyer (who might otherwise make $100 an hour if they elected to work overtime during that time instead) would be higher than for a minimum-wage employee (who in the United States might earn $7.25 an hour), which would make the former more likely to hire someone else to mow their lawn for them.

As a representation of the relationship between scarcity and choice,[2] the objective of opportunity cost is to ensure efficient use of scarce resources.[3] It incorporates all associated costs of a decision, both explicit and implicit.[4] Opportunity cost also includes the utility or economic benefit an individual lost, if it is indeed more than the monetary payment or actions taken. As an example, to go for a walk may not have any financial costs imbedded in to it. Yet, the opportunity forgone is the time spent walking which could have been used instead for other purposes such as earning an income.[3]

However, time spent chasing after an income might have health problems like in presenteeism where instead of taking a sick day one avoids it for a salary or to be seen as being active.

A production possibility frontier shows the maximum combination of factors that can be produced. For example, if services were on the x-axis of a graph and there were to be an increase in services from 20 to 25, this would lead to an opportunity cost for the goods that are on the y axis, as they would drop from 21 to 16. This means that as a result of the increase in consumption of services, the opportunity cost would be those 5 goods that have decreased.[5]

Regardless of the time of occurrence of an activity, if scarcity was non-existent then all demands of a person are satiated. It’s only through scarcity that choice becomes essential, since the use of scarce resources in one way prevents its use in another way, resulting in the need to make a selection and/or decision.[2] These decisions are in turn exposed to multiple choice outcomes.[6]

Sacrifice is a given measurement in opportunity cost of which the decision maker forgoes the opportunity of the next best alternative.[7] In other words, to disregard the equivalent utility of the best alternative choice to gain the utility of the best perceived option.[8] If there are decisions to be made that require no sacrifice then these are cost free decisions with zero opportunity cost.[9] Through the analysis of opportunity cost, a company can choose a path where the actual benefits are greater than the opportunity cost, so that limited resources can be optimally allocated to achieve maximum efficiency.

When choosing an option among multiple alternatives, the opportunity cost is the gain from the alternative we forgo when making a decision.[10] In simple terms, opportunity cost is our perceived benefit of not choosing the next best option when resources are limited.[11] Opportunity costs are not limited to monetary or financial costs.[12] The actual cost of lost time, lost production, or any other for-profit benefit shall also be considered an opportunity cost.[12] Opportunity cost is a key concept in economics, described as the fundamental relationship between scarcity and choice.[11]

Explicit costs are the direct costs of an action (business operating costs or expenses), executed either through a cash transaction or a physical transfer of resources.[4] In other words, explicit opportunity costs are the out-of-pocket costs of a firm, that are easily identifiable.[13] This means explicit costs will always have a dollar value and involve a transfer of money, e.g. paying employees.[14] With this said, these particular costs can easily be identified under the expenses of a firm's income statement and balance sheet to represent all the cash outflows of a firm.[15][14]

Examples are as follows:[13][16]

  • Land and infrastructure costs
  • Operation and maintenance costs—wages, rent, overhead, materials

Scenarios are as follows:[15]

  • If a person leaves work for an hour and spends $200 on office supplies, then the explicit costs for the individual equates to the total expenses for the office supplies of $200.
  • If a printer of a company malfunctions, then the explicit costs for the company equates to the total amount to be paid to the repair technician.

Implicit costs

Implicit costs (also referred to as implied, imputed or notional costs) are the opportunity costs of utilising resources owned by the firm that could be used for other purposes. These costs are often hidden to the naked eye and aren’t made known.[16] Unlike explicit costs, implicit opportunity costs correspond to intangibles. Hence, they cannot be clearly identified, defined or reported.[15] This means that they are costs that have already occurred within a project, without exchanging cash.[17] This could include a small business owner not taking any salary in the beginning of their tenure as a way for the business to be more profitable. As implicit costs are the result of assets, they are also not recorded for the use of accounting purposes because they do not represent any monetary losses or gains.[17] In terms of factors of production, implicit opportunity costs allow for depreciation of goods, materials and equipment that ensure the operations of a company.[18]

Examples of implicit costs regarding production are mainly resources contributed by a business owner which includes:[13][18]

  • Human labour
  • Infrastructure
  • Time

Scenarios are as follows:[15]

  • If a person leaves work for an hour to spend $200 on office supplies, and has an hourly rate of $25, then the implicit costs for the individual equates to the $25 that he/she could have earned instead.
  • If a printer of a company malfunctions, the implicit cost equates to the total production time that could have been utilized if the machine did not break down.

Sunk costs (also referred to as historical costs) are costs that have been incurred already and cannot be recovered. As sunk costs have already been incurred, they remain unchanged and should not influence present or future actions or decisions regarding benefits and costs.[19] Decision makers who recognise the insignificance of sunk costs then understand that the "consequences of choices cannot influence choice itself".[2]

From the traceability source of costs, sunk costs can be direct costs or indirect costs. If the sunk cost can be summarized as a single component, it is a direct cost; if it is caused by several products or departments, it is an indirect cost.

Analyzing from the composition of costs, sunk costs can be either fixed costs or variable costs. When a company abandons a certain component or stops processing a certain product, the sunk cost usually includes fixed costs such as rent for equipment and wages, but it also includes variable costs due to changes in time or materials. Usually, fixed costs are more likely to constitute sunk costs.

Generally speaking, the stronger the liquidity, versatility, and compatibility of the asset, the less its sunk cost will be.

A scenario is given below:[20]

A company used $5,000 for marketing and advertising on its music streaming service to increase exposure to the target market and potential consumers. In the end, the campaign proved unsuccessful. The sunk cost for the company equates to the $5,000 that was spent on the market and advertising means. This expense is to be ignored by the company in its future decisions and highlights that no additional investment should be made.

Despite the fact that sunk costs should be ignored when making future decisions, people sometimes make the mistake of thinking sunk cost matters. This is sunk cost fallacy.

Example:Steven bought a game for $100, but when he started to play it, he found it was boring rather than interesting. But Steven thinks he paid $100 for the game, so he has to play it through.

Sunk cost: $100 and the cost of the time spent playing the game. Analysis: Steven spent 100 yuan hoping to complete the whole game experience, and the game is an entertainment activity, but there is no pleasure during the game, which is already low efficiency, but Steven also chose to waste time. So it's adding more cost.


Marginal cost

The concept of marginal cost in economics is the incremental cost of each new product produced for the entire product line. For example, if you build a plane, it costs a lot of money, but when you build the 100th plane, the cost will be much lower. When building a new aircraft, the materials used may be more useful, so make as many aircraft as possible from as few materials as possible to increase the margin of profit. Marginal cost is abbreviated MC or MPC.

Marginal cost: The increase in cost caused by an additional unit of production is called marginal cost. By definition, marginal cost is equal to change in total cost (TC) (△TC) divided by the corresponding change in output (△Q) : Change in total cost/change in output: MC(Q)=△TC(Q)/△Q or MC(Q)=lim=△TC(Q)/△Q=dTC/dQ(△Q→0) (as shown in Figure 1)

In theory marginal costs represent the increase in total costs (which include both constant and variable costs) as output increases by 1 unit.

The main objective of accounting profits is to give an account of a company’s fiscal performance, typically reported on in quarters and annually. As such, accounting principles focus on tangible and measurable factors associated with operating a business such as wages and rent, and thus, do not “…infer anything about relative economic profitability.”[21] Opportunity costs are not considered in accounting profits as they have no purpose in this regard.

The purpose of calculating economic profits (and thus, opportunity costs) is to aid in better business decision-making through the inclusion of opportunity costs. In this way, a business can evaluate whether its decision and the allocation of its resources is cost-effective or not and whether resources should be reallocated.[22]

 

Simplified example of comparing economic profit vs accounting profit

Economic profit does not indicate whether or not a business decision will make money. It signifies if it is prudent to undertake a specific decision against the opportunity of undertaking a different decision. As shown in the simplified example in the image, choosing to start a business would provide $10,000 in terms of accounting profits. However, the decision to start a business would provide -$30,000 in terms of economic profits, indicating that the decision to start a business may not be prudent as the opportunity costs outweigh the profit from starting a business. In this case, where the revenue is not enough to cover the opportunity costs, the chosen option may not be the best course of action.[23] When economic profit is zero, all the explicit and implicit costs (opportunity costs) are covered by the total revenue and there is no incentive for reallocation of the resources. This condition is known as normal profit.

Several performance measures of economic profit have been derived to further improve business decision-making such as risk-adjusted return on capital (RAROC) and economic value added (EVA), which directly include a quantified opportunity cost to aid businesses in risk management and optimal allocation of resources.[24] Opportunity cost, as such, is an economic concept in economic theory which is used to maximise value through better decision-making.

In accounting, collecting, processing, and reporting information on activities and events that occur within an organization is referred to as the accounting cycle. To encourage decision-makers to efficiently allocate the resources they have (or those who have trusted them), this information is being shared with them.[25] As a result, the role of accounting has evolved in tandem with the rise of economic activity and the increasing complexity of economic structure. Accounting is not only the gathering and calculation of data that impacts a choice, but it also delves deeply into the decision-making activities of businesses through the measurement and computation of such data. In accounting, it is common practice to refer to the opportunity cost of a decision (option) as a cost.[26] The discounted cash flow method has surpassed all others as the primary method of making investment decisions, and opportunity cost has surpassed all others as an essential metric of cash outflow in making investment decisions.[27] For various reasons, the opportunity cost is critical in this form of estimation.

First and foremost, the discounted rate applied in DCF analysis is influenced by an opportunity cost, which impacts project selection and the choice of a discounting rate.[28] Using the firm's original assets in the investment means there is no need for the enterprise to utilize funds to purchase the assets, so there is no cash outflow. However, the cost of the assets must be included in the cash outflow at the current market price. Even though the asset does not result in a cash outflow, it can be sold or leased in the market to generate income and be employed in the project's cash flow. The money earned in the market represents the opportunity cost of the asset utilized in the business venture. As a result, opportunity costs must be incorporated into project planning to avoid erroneous project evaluations.[29] Only those costs directly relevant to the project will be considered in making the investment choice, and all other costs will be excluded from consideration. Modern accounting also incorporates the concept of opportunity cost into the determination of capital costs and capital structure of businesses, which must compute the cost of capital invested by the owner as a function of the ratio of human capital. In addition, opportunity costs are employed to determine to price for asset transfers between industries.

Comparative advantage versus absolute advantage

When a nation, organisation or individual can produce a product or service at a relatively lower opportunity cost compared to its competitors, it is said to have a comparative advantage. In other words, a country has comparative advantage if it gives up less of a resource to make the same number of products as the other country that has to give up more.[30]

 

A simple example of comparative advantage.

Using the simple example in the image, to make 100 tonnes of tea, Country A has to give up the production of 20 tonnes of wool which means for every 1 tonne of tea produced, 0.2 tonne of wool has to be forgone. Meanwhile, to make 30 tonnes of tea, Country B needs to sacrifice the production of 100 tonnes of wool, so for each tonne of tea, 3.3 tonnes of wool is forgone. In this case, Country A has a comparative advantage over Country B for the production of tea because it has a lower opportunity cost. On the other hand, to make 1 tonne of wool, Country A has to give up 5 tonnes of tea, while Country B would need to give up 0.3 tonnes of tea, so Country B has a comparative advantage over the production of wool.

Absolute advantage on the other hand refers to how efficiently a party can use its resources to produce goods and services compared to others, regardless of its opportunity costs. For example, if Country A can produce 1 tonne of wool using less manpower compared to Country B, then it is more efficient and has an absolute advantage over wool production, even if it does not have a comparative advantage because it has a higher opportunity cost (5 tonnes of tea).[30]

Absolute advantage refers to how efficiently resources are used whereas comparative advantage refers to how little is sacrificed in terms of opportunity cost. When a country produces what it has the comparative advantage of, even if it does not have an absolute advantage, and trades for those products it does not have a comparative advantage over, it maximises its output since the opportunity cost of its production is lower than its competitors. By focusing on specialising this way, it also maximises its level of consumption.[30]

Opportunity cost at governmental level

Much like individual decisions, it is often the case that governments must consider opportunity cost when enacting legislation. Taking universal basic healthcare as an example, the opportunity cost at the government level is quite clear. Assume that implementing basic healthcare would cost a government $1 billion: the explicit opportunity cost to implement such legislation would be a combined $1 billion that could have been spent on education, housing, transport infrastructure, environmental protection, or military defence, for example. For this particular scenario, the implicit cost is quite minimal. Only the cost of producing such legislation through human labour and the time of production would need to be accounted for.

 

Opportunity cost to implement additional hijacking prevention methods

While the previous situation’s implicit cost may have been somewhat negligible at a government level, this is not true for all scenarios. Using hijacking prevention methods following the September 11 attacks as an example, the additional burden of implicit costs is evident. To implement more sophisticated airport security systems, the United States government estimated the cost to be around $2 billion. An additional $450 million would be spent to reinforce plane doors, along with an extra $3 billion spent on sky marshals for all American flights to help further prevent future hijackings from taking place. Under this scenario, the explicit cost would be $5.45 billion. Implicit costs, however, would far outweigh this. The US government has calculated that by waiting an additional 30 minutes due to extra airport security, multiplied by an average of 800 million passengers per year with the average cost of time at $20 per hour, the total implicit cost to the US economy from such prevention methods would be upwards of $8 billion.[31] Thus the importance of recognising the opportunity cost at a governmental level is crucial in efficiently allocating government funds.

 

Demand and supply of hospital beds and days during Covid-19q

The impact of the Covid-9 pandemic that broke out in recent years on economic operations is unavoidable, the economic risks are not symmetrical, and the impact of Covid-19 is distributed differently in the global economy. Some industries have benefited from the pandemic, while others have almost gone bankrupt. One of the sectors most impacted by the COVID-19 pandemic is the public and private health system. Opportunity cost is the concept of ensuring efficient use of scarce resources,[32] a concept that is central to health economics. The massive increase in the need for intensive care has largely limited and exacerbated the department's ability to address routine health problems. The sector must consider opportunity costs in decisions related to the allocation of scarce resources, premised on improving the health of the population.[10]

However, the opportunity cost of implementing policies to the sector has limited impact in the health sector. Patients with severe symptoms of COVID-19 require close monitoring in the ICU and in therapeutic ventilator support, which is key to treating the disease.[33] In this case, scarce resources include bed days, ventilation time, and therapeutic equipment. Temporary excess demand for hospital beds from patients exceeds the number of bed days provided by the health system. The increased demand for days in bed is due to the fact that infected hospitalized patients stay in bed longer, shifting the demand curve to the right (see curve D2 in Graph1.11).[32] The number of bed days provided by the health system may be temporarily reduced as there may be a shortage of beds due to the widespread spread of the virus. If this situation becomes unmanageable, supply decreases and the supply curve shifts to the left (curve S2 in Graph1.11).[32]A perfect competition model can be used to express the concept of opportunity cost in the health sector. [34] In perfect competition, market equilibrium is understood as the point where supply and demand are exactly the same (points P and Q in Graph1.11).[32] The balance is Pareto optimal equals marginal opportunity cost. Medical allocation may result in some people being better off and others worse off. At this point, it is assumed that the market has produced the maximum outcome associated with the Pareto partial order.[32] As a result, the opportunity cost increases when other patients cannot be admitted to the ICU due to a shortage of beds.

  •  Economics portal

  • Austrian School
  • Best alternative to a negotiated agreement
  • Budget constraint
  • Economies of scale
  • Econometrics
  • Fear of missing out
  • Production-possibility frontier
  • Reduced cost aka 'opportunity cost' in linear programming
  • There ain't no such thing as a free lunch
  • Time management
  • Trade-off
  • Transaction cost
  • You can't have your cake and eat it
  • Perverse subsidies

  1. ^ Fernando, Jason. "Opportunity Cost". Investopedia. Retrieved 23 April 2021.
  2. ^ a b c Buchanan, James M. (1991). "Opportunity Cost". The World of Economics. The New Palgrave: 520–525. doi:10.1007/978-1-349-21315-3_69. ISBN 978-0-333-55177-6 – via SpringerLink.
  3. ^ a b "Economics A-Z terms beginning with O". The Economist. Retrieved 1 November 2020.
  4. ^ a b Hutchison, Emma (2017). Principles of Microeconomics. University of Victoria.
  5. ^ Pettinger, Tejvan. "Opportunity Cost Definition". Economics Help. Retrieved 30 April 2021.
  6. ^ Perron, Pierre; Bai, Justin (2003). "Computation and analysis of multiple structural change models". Journal of Applied Econometrics. 18: 1–22. doi:10.1002/jae.659. Retrieved 9 May 2022.
  7. ^ Parkin, Michael (2016). "Opportunity Cost: A reexamination". The Journal of Economic Education. 47 (1): 12–22. doi:10.1080/00220485.2015.1106361. S2CID 155746220 – via Taylor & Francis Online.
  8. ^ "A HISTORICAL VIEW OVER THE OPPORTUNITY COST -ACCOUNTING DIMENSION". ResearchGate. Retrieved 1 November 2020.
  9. ^ Burch, Earl E.; Henry, William (1974). "Opportunity and Incremental Cost: Attempt to Define in Systems Terms: A Comment. The Accounting Review". The Accounting Review. 49: 118–123. JSTOR 244804 – via JSTOR.
  10. ^ a b F., Drummond, M. (2005). Methods for the economic evaluation of health care programmes. Oxford University Press. ISBN 978-0-19-852945-3. OCLC 300939640.
  11. ^ a b M., Buchanan, James (1999). Cost and choice : an inquiry in economic theory. Liberty Fund. ISBN 0-86597-224-9. OCLC 476349821.
  12. ^ a b Robinson, Scharn (20 April 2017). "Opportunity Costs". University of Illinois Press. 1. doi:10.5406/illinois/9780252036453.003.0008.
  13. ^ a b c "Explicit and implicit costs and accounting and economic profit". Khan Academy. 2016. Retrieved 1 November 2020.
  14. ^ a b "Explicit Costs - Overview, Types of Profit, Examples". Corporate Finance Institute. Retrieved 30 April 2021.
  15. ^ a b c d "Explicit Costs: Definition and Examples". Indeed. 5 February 2020. Retrieved 1 November 2020.
  16. ^ a b Crompton, John L.; Howard, Dennis R. (2013). "Costs: The Rest of the Economic Impact Story" (PDF). Journal of Sport Management. 27 (5): 379–392. doi:10.1123/JSM.27.5.379. S2CID 13821685. Archived from the original (PDF) on 4 March 2019.
  17. ^ a b Kenton, Will. "How Implicit Costs Work". Investopedia. Retrieved 30 April 2021.
  18. ^ a b "Reading: Explicit and Implicit Costs". Lumen Learning. Retrieved 1 November 2020.
  19. ^ Devine, Kevin; O Clock, Priscilla (March 1995). "The effect on sunk costs and opportunity costs on a subjective capital allocation decision". The Mid-Atlantic Journal of Business. 31 (1): 25–38.
  20. ^ "Four Examples of Sunk Cost". Indeed. 6 October 2020. Retrieved 1 November 2020.
  21. ^ Holian, Matthew; Reza, Ali (19 July 2010). "Firm and industry effects in accounting versus economic profit data". Applied Economics Letters. 18 (6): 527–529. doi:10.1080/13504851003761756. S2CID 154558882.
  22. ^ Goolsbee, Austan; Levitt, Steven; Syverson, Chad (2019). Microeconomics (3rd ed.). Macmillan Learning. pp. 8a–8j. ISBN 9781319306793.
  23. ^ Layton, Allan; Robinson, Tim; B. Tucker III, Irvin (2015). Economics for Today (5th ed.). Cengage Australia. pp. 131–132, 479–486. ISBN 9780170276313.
  24. ^ Kimball, Ralph (1998). "Economic Profit and Performance Measurement in Banking". New England Economic Review. Federal Reserve Bank of Boston: 35–39. ISSN 0028-4726. Retrieved 13 March 2021.
  25. ^ P., Magee, Robert (1986). Advanced managerial accounting. Harper & Row. OCLC 1287886441.
  26. ^ C., Vera-Munoz, Sandra (1998). The effects of accounting knowledge and context on the omission of opportunity costs in resource allocation decisions. American Accounting Association. OCLC 926973835.
  27. ^ "Accounting and the theory of the firm*", The Firm as an Entity, Routledge, pp. 94–103, 12 April 2007, doi:10.4324/9780203931110-13, ISBN 9780429240607, retrieved 2 May 2022
  28. ^ Chung, Kee H. (1 May 1989). "Inventory Control and Trade Credit Revisited". Journal of the Operational Research Society. 40 (5): 495–498. doi:10.1057/jors.1989.77. ISSN 0160-5682. S2CID 16422604.
  29. ^ S.), Herroelen, Willy (Willy (1995). Project network models with discounted cash flows : a guided tour through recent developments. Katholieke Universiteit Leuven, Departement Toegepaste Economische Wetenschappen. OCLC 68978777.
  30. ^ a b c Layton, Allan; Robinson, Tim; B. Tucker III; Irvin (2015). Economics for Today (5th ed.). Cengage Australia. pp. 131–132, 479–486. ISBN 9780170276313.
  31. ^ Jones, Peter. "The Concept of Opportunity Cost". ER services. Retrieved 25 April 2021.
  32. ^ a b c d e Olivera, Mario J. (29 December 2020). "Opportunity cost and COVID-19: A perspective from health economics". Medical Journal of the Islamic Republic of Iran. 34: 177. doi:10.47176/mjiri.34.177. ISSN 1016-1430. PMC 8004566. PMID 33816376.
  33. ^ World Health Organization (20 May 2020). "Clinical management of severe acute respiratory infection (SARI) when COVID-19 disease is suspected. Interim guidance". Pediatria I Medycyna Rodzinna. 16 (1): 9–26. doi:10.15557/pimr.2020.0003. ISSN 1734-1531. S2CID 219964509.
  34. ^ A., Lipsey, R. G. Chrystal, K. (2007). Economics. Oxford University Press. ISBN 978-0-19-928641-6. OCLC 475315028.

  • The Opportunity Cost of Economics Education by Robert H. Frank

Retrieved from "https://en.wikipedia.org/w/index.php?title=Opportunity_cost&oldid=1089074586"