The most important factor in determining the long run profit potential in monopolistic competition is

Monopolistic competition characterizes an industry in which many firms offer products or services that are similar (but not perfect) substitutes. Barriers to entry and exit in a monopolistic competitive industry are low, and the decisions of any one firm do not directly affect those of its competitors. Monopolistic competition is closely related to the business strategy of brand differentiation.

  • Monopolistic competition occurs when an industry has many firms offering products that are similar but not identical.
  • Unlike a monopoly, these firms have little power to curtail supply or raise prices to increase profits.
  • Firms in monopolistic competition typically try to differentiate their products in order to achieve above-market returns.
  • Heavy advertising and marketing are common among firms in monopolistic competition and some economists criticize this as wasteful.

Monopolistic competition is a middle ground between monopoly and perfect competition (a purely theoretical state) and combines elements of each. The term was first used in the 1930s by economists Edward Chamberlain and Joan Robinson, to describe the competition between firms with similar, but not identical, product offerings. All firms in monopolistic competition have the same relatively low degree of market power; they are all price makers.

In the long run, demand is highly elastic, meaning that it is sensitive to price changes. In the short run, economic profit is positive, but it approaches zero in the long run. Firms in monopolistic competition tend to advertise heavily.

Monopolistic competition is characterized by heavy spending on advertising and marketing, which some economists characterize as a waste of resources.

Monopolistic competition is a form of competition that characterizes a number of industries that are familiar to consumers in their day-to-day lives. Examples include restaurants, hair salons, clothing, and consumer electronics. To illustrate the characteristics of monopolistic competition, we'll use the example of household cleaning products.

Say you've just moved into a new house and want to stock up on cleaning supplies. Go to the appropriate aisle in a grocery store, and you'll see that any given item—dish soap, hand soap, laundry detergent, surface disinfectant, toilet bowl cleaner, etc.—is available in a number of varieties. For each purchase you need to make, perhaps five or six firms will be competing for your business.

Because the products all serve the same purpose, there are relatively few options for sellers to differentiate their offerings from other competing firms. There might be "discount" varieties that are of lower quality, but it is difficult to tell whether the higher-priced options are in fact any better. This uncertainty results from imperfect information: the average consumer does not know the precise differences between the various products, or what the fair price for any of them is.

Monopolistic competition tends to lead to heavy marketing because different firms need to distinguish broadly similar products. One company might opt to lower the price of their cleaning product, sacrificing a higher profit margin in exchange—ideally—for higher sales. Another might take the opposite route, raising the price and using packaging that suggests quality and sophistication.

A third might sell itself as more eco-friendly, using "green" imagery and displaying a stamp of approval from an environmental certifier. In reality, every one of the brands might be equally effective.

Hair salons, restaurants, clothing, and consumer electronics are all examples of industries with monopolistic competition. Each company offers products that are similar to others in the same industry. However, they can distinguish themselves through marketing and branding.

Firms in monopolistic competition face a significantly different business environment than those in either a monopoly or perfect competition. In addition to competing to reduce costs or scaling up production, companies in monopolistic competition can also distinguish themselves through other means.

Monopolistic competition implies that there are enough firms in the industry so that one firm's decision does not require other companies to change their behavior. In an oligopoly, a price cut by one firm can set off a price war, but this is not the case for monopolistic competition.

As in a monopoly, firms in monopolistic competition are price setters or makers, rather than price takers. However, their nominal ability to set prices is effectively offset by the fact that demand for their products is highly price-elastic. In order to actually raise their prices, the firms must be able to differentiate their products from those of their competitors by increasing their quality, real or perceived. 

Due to the range of similar offerings, demand is highly elastic in monopolistic competition. In other words, demand is very responsive to price changes. If your favorite multipurpose surface cleaner suddenly costs 20% more, you probably won't hesitate to switch to an alternative, and your countertops probably won't know the difference.

In the short run, firms can make excess economic profits. However, because barriers to entry are low, other firms have an incentive to enter the market, increasing the competition, until overall economic profit is zero. Note that economic profits are not the same as accounting profits; a firm that posts a positive net income can have zero economic profit because the latter incorporates opportunity costs.

Economists who study monopolistic competition often highlight the social cost of this type of market structure. Firms in monopolistic competition expend large amounts of real resources on advertising and other forms of marketing.

When there is a real difference between the products of different firms but that the consumer might not be aware of, these expenditures can be useful. However, if it is instead the case that the products are near-perfect substitutes, which is likely in monopolistic competition, then real resources spent on advertising and marketing represent a kind of wasteful rent-seeking behavior, which produces a deadweight loss to society.

Monopolistic competitive industries generally consist of many different companies that produce products that are similar but not identical. These companies spend many of their resources on advertising to make their products stand out. Competition is rife and barriers to entry are low, meaning companies must work hard and be creative to squeeze out a profit and be aware that hiking prices too much might lead customers to opt for an alternative.

Monopolistic competition is present in many familiar industries, including restaurants, hair salons, clothing, and consumer electronics. A good example would be Burger King and McDonald's. Both are fast food chains that target a similar market and offer similar products and services. These two companies are actively competing with one another, as well as countless other restaurants, and seek to differentiate themselves through brand recognition, price, and by offering slightly different food and drink packages.

A monopoly is when a single company dominates an industry. This lack of competition means the company can set prices as it pleases, provided, of course, that there is demand for what it offers.

Monopolistic competitive companies don’t enjoy this luxury. Such entities must compete with others, restricting their ability to substantially hike prices and circumvent the natural laws of supply and demand. Monopolistic competition is viewed as healthier for the economy and is much more common than monopolies, which are generally frowned upon in free-market nations because they can lead to price-gouging and deteriorating quality due to a lack of alternative choices.